歡迎來(lái)到裝配圖網(wǎng)! | 幫助中心 裝配圖網(wǎng)zhuangpeitu.com!
裝配圖網(wǎng)
ImageVerifierCode 換一換
首頁(yè) 裝配圖網(wǎng) > 資源分類 > DOC文檔下載  

農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)[文獻(xiàn)翻譯]

  • 資源ID:30745443       資源大小:62.50KB        全文頁(yè)數(shù):13頁(yè)
  • 資源格式: DOC        下載積分:15積分
快捷下載 游客一鍵下載
會(huì)員登錄下載
微信登錄下載
三方登錄下載: 微信開(kāi)放平臺(tái)登錄 支付寶登錄   QQ登錄   微博登錄  
二維碼
微信掃一掃登錄
下載資源需要15積分
郵箱/手機(jī):
溫馨提示:
用戶名和密碼都是您填寫(xiě)的郵箱或者手機(jī)號(hào),方便查詢和重復(fù)下載(系統(tǒng)自動(dòng)生成)
支付方式: 支付寶    微信支付   
驗(yàn)證碼:   換一換

 
賬號(hào):
密碼:
驗(yàn)證碼:   換一換
  忘記密碼?
    
友情提示
2、PDF文件下載后,可能會(huì)被瀏覽器默認(rèn)打開(kāi),此種情況可以點(diǎn)擊瀏覽器菜單,保存網(wǎng)頁(yè)到桌面,就可以正常下載了。
3、本站不支持迅雷下載,請(qǐng)使用電腦自帶的IE瀏覽器,或者360瀏覽器、谷歌瀏覽器下載即可。
4、本站資源下載后的文檔和圖紙-無(wú)水印,預(yù)覽文檔經(jīng)過(guò)壓縮,下載后原文更清晰。
5、試題試卷類文檔,如果標(biāo)題沒(méi)有明確說(shuō)明有答案則都視為沒(méi)有答案,請(qǐng)知曉。

農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)[文獻(xiàn)翻譯]

本科畢業(yè)論文外文翻譯原文外文題目Theme: Rural Finance Institutions and System Models of Rural Financial Institutions 出 處:Institute of Rural Development 作 者:Manfred Zeller 原 文:The Role of Rural Finance for Agricultural and Economic Growth, Food Security and Poverty ReductionSecond, while agriculture is, relatively speaking, a declining sector in the course ofdevelopment, in many developing countries it is still a leading economic sector, the main exporter, and the major employer, especially for the poor and women. Improved financial markets accelerate agricultural and rural growth. Financial services assist households in maintaining food security and smoothing consumption, thereby safeguarding or enhancing labor productivity , the most important production factor of the poor. Because of agricultures strong forward and backward multiplier effects for the overall economy, economic growth in agriculture especially in subsectors that directly or indirectly benefit smallholders, tenants, and wage laborers is a key precondition for overall economic growth and poverty reduction. At present, most of the poor still live in rural areas. Any student of an introductory course in micro-economics or development economics learns that access to savings, credit and insurance services can have beneficial effects on households and their enterprises and therefore on economic growth, and that microfinance in particular may also contribute to more equitable growth. Access to credit, however, has an economic benefit only if and when that access generates a broadly defined net economic surplus after having deducted the private and social costs of loan provision (including the opportunity costs of scarce public funds in alternative poverty reduction policies). While the evidence on the impact of credit on household welfare, agricultural technology adoption, and on agricultural sector growth is mixed4 , many practical constraints (i.e. time and money) and methodological difficulties in estimating the impact of a policy or project with a reasonable probability of error exist Simple common sense tells us that savers who continue to deposit money for different motives, borrowers who continue to repay their loans, and clients paying regular premiums for health and life insurance over long periods actually derive an economic benefit.CHANGING WISDOMS AND POLICY OBJECTIVES IN RURAL FINANCESince the mid 1980s, there has been a paradigm shift in financial policy (including rural finance) from subsidized credit to financial systems development.The old paradigm of sector directed, supply led and subsidized credit has been based on faulty assumptions about the willingness and ability of poor farmers and other entrepreneurs to pay for financial services, which led to faulty policy design and implementation.The new paradigm departs not from the need, but from the demand (i.e. willingness and ability to pay market prices) for savings, credit and insurance services by farmers and other entrepreneurs. Instead it focuses on building sustainable financial institutions and systems, and introduced the operational policy objective of financial sustainability of MFIs. The new paradigm recognizes that high transaction costs and risks that partly result from information asymmetries and moral hazard problems for both financial intermediaries and clients are some of the root causes of the gap between demand and supply. Therefore, the new paradigm places emphasis on searching for technological and institutional innovations (including suitable governance and incentive structures) to reduce the costs and risks of financial intermediation. Thenew paradigm recognizes the possibility of market as well as government failure (i.e. institutional failure in general), and negates the thesis put forward by proponents of market liberalization that a “financial system which is not repressed would by itself function optimally”. The new paradigm in contrast sees financial market liberalization (e.g. with respect to interest rate formation) as a necessary but not sufficient condition for deepening financial systems. Moreover, as the required technological and institutional innovations needed to deepen the financial system and to serve poorer segments of the population can be readily copied by for-profit financial institutions, the resulting free-rider problem prevents the private sector from sufficiently investing (compared to socially optimal levels) in such innovations. In conclusion, public investment in pro-poor (and pro rural) financial innovation is required.This holds true not only for microfinance, but for rural finance as well. Thus, public investment in rural finance can be justified, for example, to fund (action)-research and promising institutional start-ups as well as institutional expansion until reaching financial sustainability within reasonable time periods, and to support pilot experiments with promising new products, technology or technical assistance, such as for training of staff and transfer of best practices. Given the long gestation periods required in building sustainable institutions, public investment in institution-building requires long-term planning horizons with operational flexibility in instruments and timing. The required public investment in rural finance is more labor and knowledge-intensive, and far less capital-intensive than past investments following the old paradigm. The triangle of microfinance: financial sustainability, outreach, and welfare impactInternationally agreed principal objectives of development cooperation are the United Nations Millennium Development Goals (MDGs). These set targets to reduce poverty and make improvements in the various dimensions of poverty (or welfare) such as education, health, nutrition and womens empowermentFollowing the concept of a logical framework, (financial) sector policy objectives need therefore to be consistent with these principal objectives Microfinance as well as rural financial policy has to be evaluated against three objectives: financial sustainability, breadth and depth of outreach, and the welfare impact.Financial sector policy can support the Millenium Development Goals (and thus poverty reduction) in two ways: Indirectly, through supporting a sustainable financial system as a precondition for economic and social development. This indirect pathway includes causal chains that can be summarized under the thesis of poverty reduction through economic growth. An example of one of these causal chains is that owners of wealthier enterprises who use the financial services create additional demand for goods and services of the poor thus increasing their income.Directly, by increasing the access of poor people to financial services. Governments and donors may differ in their perceptions about the relative effectiveness and efficiency of the two pathways. Indeed, which one may receive more emphasis has to necessarily vary with country- specific conditions. It follows that governments and donors also differ in their relative emphasis on the three objectives in micro- and rural finance, i.e. financial sustainability, depth of outreach, and welfare impact. This, of course, influences their view on the relative efficiency of different types of financial institutions, and thereby influences how financial policies are designed in practice and how the institutional landscape evolves. Because of market imperfections, the state has a legitimate role for investing in financial systems development. However, given the possibility of government failure(i.e. governments may not be able to correct market failures), and social opportunity costs of public funds, there are of course also limitations of public investment in finance. There has been a shift in paradigm in rural finance in the late 1980s, and much of this can be traced to the failures of subsidized small farmer credit and the successes of a few MFIs. The objectives of financial policy have changed along with the paradigm shift.Initially, the focus was on improving the outreach of MFIs to the poor, that is, serve more of the poor (breadth of outreach) and more of the poorest of the poor (depth of outreach).Eventually, the objective of sustainability of financial institutions took on great importance. Following the work of Ohio State University and other institutions in the 1980s, the view emerged that the building of lasting, permanent financial institutions requires that they become financially sustainable, that is, they cover their costs. Some analysts (for example, Christen et al. 1995; Otero and Rhyne 1994) argued that increasing the depth of outreach and financial sustainability are compatible objectives in the sense that increasing the scale of operations will also increase the absolute number of poor people among clients: “It is scale, not exclusive focus, that determines whether significant outreach to the poor will occur”. Several other authors present analysis that supports the notion of a trade-off between improving depth of outreach, i.e. reaching relatively poorer people, and achieving financial sustainabilityThe trade-off stems from the fact that transaction costs have a large fixed cost component so that unit costs for smaller savings deposits or smaller loans are high compared to larger financial transactions. This law of decreasing unit transaction costs with larger size transactions generates the trade-off between improved outreach to the poor and financial sustainability, irrespective of the lending technology used. To cover the higher costs of these loans, interest rates need to either be set higher, or the MFI may follow a strategy of using economies of scale, scope and risk to cross subsidize smaller loans. Breadth of outreach (in terms of number of clientele) and depth of outreach (at present measured through the very imprecise, but widely used indicator of average loan size (or balance) in relation to per-capita GDP are now regularly reported, e.g. in the Microbanking Bulletin Wenner states that depth of outreach, specified as target maximum average loan size, has become a criteria used by the IDB for certain instruments of (rural) microfinance policy.Financial sustainability of the financial institution and outreach to the poor are only two of the policy objectives of microfinance. The third policy objective relates to the impact of financial systems development, particularly on poverty reduction. When policy intervention and direct support for institution building requires public investments funded either by domestic or foreign taxes or donations, the question arises about the payoff or impact, for example in terms of economic growth and alleviation of poverty and food insecurity.Institutional innovation in microfinance following the new paradigm has relied on financial support by donors and governments and by other social investors such as philanthropic foundations. In fact, many, but not all, MFIs that reach large numbers of female and male clients below the poverty line require continued state or donor transfers to fully cover costs Moreover, most, if not all, of the MFIs featured in the Microbanking Bulletin that already reached financial sustainability have required public investment at some point in their existence, be it to enable technical assistance or to receive capital for going to scale so as to reduce unit costs. Some may consider these funds provided by governments, donors and other social investors as subsidies (with a negative connotation), but from a policy perspective- these funds constitute public investment (be it good or bad investment) in institution and systems building. Such publicinvestments are justified from a public policy perspective if the discounted social benefits of public investment in microfinance are expected to outweigh the social costs. These costs include the opportunity costs of foregoing the net social benefits of other public investments, such as in primary education . The subsidy dependence index has become a widely accepted operational measure to quantify the amount of social costs involved in supporting the operations of a financial institutionAddressing the policy question of whether such public investments are economically not financially- sustainable requires a comparison of social costs with social benefits. This consideration raises welfare impact as an important third objective of microfinance. The triangle of microfinance, which reflects the three objectives of financial sustainability, outreach, and impact, is represented in Figure 1.MFIs attempt to contribute to these objectives (either indirectly through pursuance of financial sustainability leading to scale and serving many clients or directly through targeting poorer segments of the population) but many stress one particular objective over the other two. Donors, governments, and other social investors also differ in their relative emphasis on the three objectives. Some MFIs may produce large impacts (especially if financial services are coupled with non-financial services addressing other constraints of the poor) but achieve limited outreach. Others may make smaller impacts but are highly financially sustainable with a large breadth of outreach, and investments in such institutions may have a high cost efficiency in reducing poverty. The potential trade-offs between depth of outreach and financial sustainability have been noted, but they may also exist between impact and financial sustainability. As Sharma and Buchenrieder argue, the impact of finance can be enhanced through complementary non financial services, such as business or marketing services or training of borrowers that raise the profitability of loan financed projects. Complementary services are sometimes offered by MFIs but supplying them increases the complexity of the operation and its costs, thereby foregoing efficiency gains from specialization and jeopardizing financial sustainability if the additional costs are not covered by borrowers (which almost never happens).There may also be trade-offs between impact and depth of outreach. The impact assessment studies reviewed by Sharma and Buchenrieder suggest that the very poor can benefit from microfinance largely by smoothing their consumption through improved management of their savings and through borrowing. Those just above or justbelow the poverty line can use loans more effectively for productive purposes, which ultimately raise their income and asset base. Thus, expanding financial services may improve the welfare of the very poor, but not necessarily lift them out of poverty because of their lack of access to markets, technology, knowledge, and other factors that expand the production frontier.These potential trade-offs exist in urban as well as rural finance, and must be addressed when financial institutions develop their business plans and decide between marketing their services to only the very poor, to a mix of clients clustered around the poverty line, or to owners of small- and medium-size enterprises. This raises the question of what outcome is considered most socially desirable or optimal. And giving an answer “is a matter of value judgment” (Morduch, 1999c). For example, is public support more desired for MFIs that specifically target the poor, such as those in Bangladesh that use specific wealth criteria in an attempt to exclude those living above the poverty line?These questions on trade-offs arise when donors and policy-makers consider investing in rural finance.There are also potential synergies among the three objectives of microfinance policy. First, financial sustainability is likely to be perceived by potential clients as a critical indicator of MFI permanence, and will influence their decision about whether it is worthwhile in the long run to become and stay clients. Thus, greater financial sustainability can positively influence outreach. This synergy is even more important for savers who must have faith in the permanence of the institution to which they entrust their savings. No one will save with an institution that is considered temporary. Second,striving for financial sustainability forces MFIs to be sensitive to client demand and induces them to improve products, operations, and outreach. Better financial products, in turn, generate greater economic benefits for clients, and thus greater impact.Clearly, both the institutionalist and welfarist group among microfinance have good arguments, and can provide empirical evidence supporting their favored synergies or trade-offs. However, only a public-welfare perspective can consistently unite these different arguments. In addition, a public welfare perspective using cost-benefit-analysis- can, beyond micro and rural finance, help overcome constraints in other areas (communications, markets, health, and education, etc) which hinder the economic,social and human development of the poor and, also of micro and rural finance.The outer circle represents the external environment including the macro-economic and sectoral policies that affect directly or indirectly the performance of financial institutions. Innovations at the institutional level (the inner circle) and improvements in the policy environment (the outer circle) contribute to improving the overall performance of the financial system and its institutions.While finance is certainly not charity, institution-building and innovation can be significantly fostered by public investment. Such investment has to be appraised with the same evaluation criteria as for any other public investment. The social benefit-cost ratio of public support for MFIs will be affected by many factors, including the macro policy, socio-economic and agro-ecological environment. Some environments may be so hostile to financial-sector development that public investments in MFIs will certainly generate a negative social return, whereas in others the same investment can be highly profitable.譯 文:主題:農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)的模型農(nóng)業(yè)和經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)、糧食安全并消除貧困之農(nóng)村金融的角色雖然農(nóng)業(yè)是呈下降趨勢(shì),相比較而言,在很多發(fā)展中國(guó)家,這仍然是一個(gè)主要經(jīng)濟(jì)部門(mén),主要出口國(guó),和主要的雇主,尤其是對(duì)窮人和婦女。改善金融市場(chǎng)促進(jìn)農(nóng)業(yè)和農(nóng)村發(fā)展。在維持金融服務(wù)協(xié)助家庭食品安全,保持消費(fèi),從而保護(hù)或提高勞動(dòng)生產(chǎn)率,最重要的生產(chǎn)要素是窮人。因?yàn)檗r(nóng)業(yè)方面強(qiáng)大的向前和向后乘數(shù)效果,整個(gè)經(jīng)濟(jì),經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)在農(nóng)業(yè)特別是在多個(gè)界別分組小農(nóng)利益直接或者間接的租戶,和工資勞動(dòng)者,是一個(gè)關(guān)鍵的前提總體經(jīng)濟(jì)的增長(zhǎng)并消除貧困。目前絕大多數(shù)的窮人仍然生活在農(nóng)村地區(qū)。任何學(xué)生的微觀經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)導(dǎo)論課程或發(fā)展經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)得知進(jìn)入儲(chǔ)蓄、信貸和保險(xiǎn)服務(wù)的家庭都有有利作用及其企業(yè),因此對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)特別是,小額信貸也可能導(dǎo)致更合理的增長(zhǎng)。信貸渠道,然而,只有經(jīng)濟(jì)效益,當(dāng)這個(gè)訪問(wèn)生成一個(gè)廣義的定義以后經(jīng)濟(jì)凈盈余的私人和社會(huì)成本扣除貸款條款(包括機(jī)會(huì)成本有限的公共資金替代扶貧政策)。而影響的證據(jù)信用對(duì)家庭福利、農(nóng)業(yè)技術(shù)的采用,農(nóng)業(yè)部門(mén)增長(zhǎng),許多實(shí)際的約束mixed4(即時(shí)間和金錢(qián))和方法上的困難在估計(jì)的政策或影響項(xiàng)目的合理概率誤差的存在。簡(jiǎn)單的常識(shí)告訴我們,儲(chǔ)戶存錢(qián)的動(dòng)機(jī)不同,借款人繼續(xù)償還貸款,和客戶定期支付健康和人壽保險(xiǎn)的保險(xiǎn)費(fèi),實(shí)際推導(dǎo)出在長(zhǎng)時(shí)期內(nèi)的經(jīng)濟(jì)效益。智慧和政策目標(biāo)改變農(nóng)村金融自上個(gè)世紀(jì)八十年代,有了一個(gè)范式轉(zhuǎn)換的金融政策,包括農(nóng)村金融信貸從補(bǔ)貼金融體系的發(fā)展。舊范例扇形的指導(dǎo),供應(yīng)領(lǐng)導(dǎo)和補(bǔ)貼的信用證已經(jīng)根據(jù)有能力的企業(yè)家們和貧苦農(nóng)民錯(cuò)誤的假定意愿支付金融服務(wù),導(dǎo)致錯(cuò)誤的政策的設(shè)計(jì)和實(shí)施。撇開(kāi)的新范式的需求,不從農(nóng)民和其他的企業(yè)家的意愿和能力(即按市場(chǎng)價(jià)格)、信用和存款保險(xiǎn)服務(wù)的需求出發(fā)。相反,它集中于建立可持續(xù)的金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng),并介紹了經(jīng)營(yíng)政策目標(biāo)MFIs金融的可持續(xù)性發(fā)展。新范式中承認(rèn)高昂的交易成本和風(fēng)險(xiǎn),部分是由于信息不對(duì)稱和道德風(fēng)險(xiǎn)問(wèn)題,對(duì)于金融中間人,客戶是供給問(wèn)題的根源。因此,新范式尋找重點(diǎn)是技術(shù)和制度創(chuàng)新(包括適當(dāng)?shù)墓芾砗图?lì)結(jié)構(gòu)的),以減少金融中介的成本和風(fēng)險(xiǎn)。認(rèn)識(shí)的新范式的可能是 “政府失敗”的市場(chǎng)(即總的來(lái)說(shuō)是制度的失敗所造成),并否認(rèn)科學(xué)家提出的市場(chǎng)自由化,即“金融系統(tǒng)并不是壓抑自己會(huì)功能最佳”。 新范式中與金融市場(chǎng)的自由化(如看到關(guān)于利率形成)是一種必要的但不充分條件,能深化金融系統(tǒng)。此外,當(dāng)技術(shù)和制度創(chuàng)新需要深化金融系統(tǒng)時(shí),服務(wù)貧困階層的需要可以很容易復(fù)制營(yíng)利性的金融機(jī)構(gòu),由此產(chǎn)生的問(wèn)題普遍存在并制約著私營(yíng)部門(mén)的充分投資(比社會(huì)最優(yōu)水平創(chuàng)新)。總之,公共投資,扶貧(和專業(yè)人士)對(duì)農(nóng)村金融創(chuàng)新是必需的。這個(gè)問(wèn)題不僅小額貸款存在,而且農(nóng)村金融也存在。因此,公共投資,農(nóng)村金融可以證明,例如,基金(行動(dòng))研究和初創(chuàng)企業(yè)良好的制度以及制度擴(kuò)張直到達(dá)到在合理的時(shí)間金融可持續(xù)發(fā)展,并支持飛行員實(shí)驗(yàn)和希望的新產(chǎn)品、技術(shù)或技術(shù)支持,比如員工培訓(xùn)和轉(zhuǎn)讓的最佳途徑。建立可持續(xù)要求事業(yè)組織、社會(huì)投資機(jī)構(gòu)建立了需要長(zhǎng)期規(guī)劃和準(zhǔn)備靈活操作視野設(shè)備以及把握時(shí)機(jī)。所需的公共投資,農(nóng)村金融體系更多的是勞動(dòng)和知識(shí)密集型,并遠(yuǎn)比以往少一些資本密集型投資證明舊范例。三角小額金融借貸:金融可持續(xù)發(fā)展、擴(kuò)大服務(wù)、福利的影響全球協(xié)商一致的發(fā)展主要目的合作是中國(guó)在聯(lián)合國(guó)千年發(fā)展目標(biāo)(實(shí)現(xiàn))。這些目標(biāo)是減少貧困和改進(jìn)各種維度的貧窮(或福利,如:教育、健康、營(yíng)養(yǎng)和婦女的授權(quán)。證明的邏輯框架的概念,金融部門(mén)政策因此需要符合這些主要的目標(biāo):小額信貸以及農(nóng)村金融政策已被評(píng)估對(duì)三大目標(biāo)金融可持續(xù)的、廣度和深度外展,和福利的影響。金融部門(mén)政策支持千禧年發(fā)展目標(biāo),從而減少貧困)兩種方式:間接通過(guò)支持可持續(xù)的金融系統(tǒng)的先決條件的經(jīng)濟(jì)和社會(huì)發(fā)展。這種間接路徑包括因果鏈條下,其減少貧困的論文通過(guò)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)。例之一,這些原因鏈?zhǔn)菢I(yè)主企業(yè)進(jìn)入使用金融服務(wù)創(chuàng)造額外對(duì)商品和服務(wù)的需求的窮人從而增加收入。直接通過(guò)提高窮人的進(jìn)入金融服務(wù)。政府以及捐贈(zèng)人他們對(duì)自己也有所區(qū)別走有效性和效率的兩個(gè)通路。事實(shí)上,讓你可接受更多的重點(diǎn)不同

注意事項(xiàng)

本文(農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)[文獻(xiàn)翻譯])為本站會(huì)員(仙***)主動(dòng)上傳,裝配圖網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)上載內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯。 若此文所含內(nèi)容侵犯了您的版權(quán)或隱私,請(qǐng)立即通知裝配圖網(wǎng)(點(diǎn)擊聯(lián)系客服),我們立即給予刪除!

溫馨提示:如果因?yàn)榫W(wǎng)速或其他原因下載失敗請(qǐng)重新下載,重復(fù)下載不扣分。




關(guān)于我們 - 網(wǎng)站聲明 - 網(wǎng)站地圖 - 資源地圖 - 友情鏈接 - 網(wǎng)站客服 - 聯(lián)系我們

copyright@ 2023-2025  zhuangpeitu.com 裝配圖網(wǎng)版權(quán)所有   聯(lián)系電話:18123376007

備案號(hào):ICP2024067431號(hào)-1 川公網(wǎng)安備51140202000466號(hào)


本站為文檔C2C交易模式,即用戶上傳的文檔直接被用戶下載,本站只是中間服務(wù)平臺(tái),本站所有文檔下載所得的收益歸上傳人(含作者)所有。裝配圖網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)上載內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯。若文檔所含內(nèi)容侵犯了您的版權(quán)或隱私,請(qǐng)立即通知裝配圖網(wǎng),我們立即給予刪除!