農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)[文獻(xiàn)翻譯]
《農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)[文獻(xiàn)翻譯]》由會員分享,可在線閱讀,更多相關(guān)《農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)[文獻(xiàn)翻譯](13頁珍藏版)》請?jiān)谘b配圖網(wǎng)上搜索。
1、本科畢業(yè)論文外文翻譯原文外文題目Theme: Rural Finance Institutions and System Models of Rural Financial Institutions 出 處:Institute of Rural Development 作 者:Manfred Zeller 原 文:The Role of Rural Finance for Agricultural and Economic Growth, Food Security and Poverty ReductionSecond, while agriculture is, relatively sp
2、eaking, a declining sector in the course ofdevelopment, in many developing countries it is still a leading economic sector, the main exporter, and the major employer, especially for the poor and women. Improved financial markets accelerate agricultural and rural growth. Financial services assist hou
3、seholds in maintaining food security and smoothing consumption, thereby safeguarding or enhancing labor productivity , the most important production factor of the poor. Because of agricultures strong forward and backward multiplier effects for the overall economy, economic growth in agriculture espe
4、cially in subsectors that directly or indirectly benefit smallholders, tenants, and wage laborers is a key precondition for overall economic growth and poverty reduction. At present, most of the poor still live in rural areas. Any student of an introductory course in micro-economics or development e
5、conomics learns that access to savings, credit and insurance services can have beneficial effects on households and their enterprises and therefore on economic growth, and that microfinance in particular may also contribute to more equitable growth. Access to credit, however, has an economic benefit
6、 only if and when that access generates a broadly defined net economic surplus after having deducted the private and social costs of loan provision (including the opportunity costs of scarce public funds in alternative poverty reduction policies). While the evidence on the impact of credit on househ
7、old welfare, agricultural technology adoption, and on agricultural sector growth is mixed4 , many practical constraints (i.e. time and money) and methodological difficulties in estimating the impact of a policy or project with a reasonable probability of error exist Simple common sense tells us that
8、 savers who continue to deposit money for different motives, borrowers who continue to repay their loans, and clients paying regular premiums for health and life insurance over long periods actually derive an economic benefit.CHANGING WISDOMS AND POLICY OBJECTIVES IN RURAL FINANCESince the mid 1980s
9、, there has been a paradigm shift in financial policy (including rural finance) from subsidized credit to financial systems development.The old paradigm of sector directed, supply led and subsidized credit has been based on faulty assumptions about the willingness and ability of poor farmers and oth
10、er entrepreneurs to pay for financial services, which led to faulty policy design and implementation.The new paradigm departs not from the need, but from the demand (i.e. willingness and ability to pay market prices) for savings, credit and insurance services by farmers and other entrepreneurs. Inst
11、ead it focuses on building sustainable financial institutions and systems, and introduced the operational policy objective of financial sustainability of MFIs. The new paradigm recognizes that high transaction costs and risks that partly result from information asymmetries and moral hazard problems
12、for both financial intermediaries and clients are some of the root causes of the gap between demand and supply. Therefore, the new paradigm places emphasis on searching for technological and institutional innovations (including suitable governance and incentive structures) to reduce the costs and ri
13、sks of financial intermediation. Thenew paradigm recognizes the possibility of market as well as government failure (i.e. institutional failure in general), and negates the thesis put forward by proponents of market liberalization that a “financial system which is not repressed would by itself funct
14、ion optimally”. The new paradigm in contrast sees financial market liberalization (e.g. with respect to interest rate formation) as a necessary but not sufficient condition for deepening financial systems. Moreover, as the required technological and institutional innovations needed to deepen the fin
15、ancial system and to serve poorer segments of the population can be readily copied by for-profit financial institutions, the resulting free-rider problem prevents the private sector from sufficiently investing (compared to socially optimal levels) in such innovations. In conclusion, public investmen
16、t in pro-poor (and pro rural) financial innovation is required.This holds true not only for microfinance, but for rural finance as well. Thus, public investment in rural finance can be justified, for example, to fund (action)-research and promising institutional start-ups as well as institutional ex
17、pansion until reaching financial sustainability within reasonable time periods, and to support pilot experiments with promising new products, technology or technical assistance, such as for training of staff and transfer of best practices. Given the long gestation periods required in building sustai
18、nable institutions, public investment in institution-building requires long-term planning horizons with operational flexibility in instruments and timing. The required public investment in rural finance is more labor and knowledge-intensive, and far less capital-intensive than past investments follo
19、wing the old paradigm. The triangle of microfinance: financial sustainability, outreach, and welfare impactInternationally agreed principal objectives of development cooperation are the United Nations Millennium Development Goals (MDGs). These set targets to reduce poverty and make improvements in t
20、he various dimensions of poverty (or welfare) such as education, health, nutrition and womens empowermentFollowing the concept of a logical framework, (financial) sector policy objectives need therefore to be consistent with these principal objectives Microfinance as well as rural financial policy h
21、as to be evaluated against three objectives: financial sustainability, breadth and depth of outreach, and the welfare impact.Financial sector policy can support the Millenium Development Goals (and thus poverty reduction) in two ways: Indirectly, through supporting a sustainable financial system as
22、a precondition for economic and social development. This indirect pathway includes causal chains that can be summarized under the thesis of poverty reduction through economic growth. An example of one of these causal chains is that owners of wealthier enterprises who use the financial services creat
23、e additional demand for goods and services of the poor thus increasing their income.Directly, by increasing the access of poor people to financial services. Governments and donors may differ in their perceptions about the relative effectiveness and efficiency of the two pathways. Indeed, which one m
24、ay receive more emphasis has to necessarily vary with country- specific conditions. It follows that governments and donors also differ in their relative emphasis on the three objectives in micro- and rural finance, i.e. financial sustainability, depth of outreach, and welfare impact. This, of course
25、, influences their view on the relative efficiency of different types of financial institutions, and thereby influences how financial policies are designed in practice and how the institutional landscape evolves. Because of market imperfections, the state has a legitimate role for investing in finan
26、cial systems development. However, given the possibility of government failure(i.e. governments may not be able to correct market failures), and social opportunity costs of public funds, there are of course also limitations of public investment in finance. There has been a shift in paradigm in rural
27、 finance in the late 1980s, and much of this can be traced to the failures of subsidized small farmer credit and the successes of a few MFIs. The objectives of financial policy have changed along with the paradigm shift.Initially, the focus was on improving the outreach of MFIs to the poor, that is,
28、 serve more of the poor (breadth of outreach) and more of the poorest of the poor (depth of outreach).Eventually, the objective of sustainability of financial institutions took on great importance. Following the work of Ohio State University and other institutions in the 1980s, the view emerged that
29、 the building of lasting, permanent financial institutions requires that they become financially sustainable, that is, they cover their costs. Some analysts (for example, Christen et al. 1995; Otero and Rhyne 1994) argued that increasing the depth of outreach and financial sustainability are compati
30、ble objectives in the sense that increasing the scale of operations will also increase the absolute number of poor people among clients: “It is scale, not exclusive focus, that determines whether significant outreach to the poor will occur”. Several other authors present analysis that supports the n
31、otion of a trade-off between improving depth of outreach, i.e. reaching relatively poorer people, and achieving financial sustainabilityThe trade-off stems from the fact that transaction costs have a large fixed cost component so that unit costs for smaller savings deposits or smaller loans are high
32、 compared to larger financial transactions. This law of decreasing unit transaction costs with larger size transactions generates the trade-off between improved outreach to the poor and financial sustainability, irrespective of the lending technology used. To cover the higher costs of these loans, i
33、nterest rates need to either be set higher, or the MFI may follow a strategy of using economies of scale, scope and risk to cross subsidize smaller loans. Breadth of outreach (in terms of number of clientele) and depth of outreach (at present measured through the very imprecise, but widely used indi
34、cator of average loan size (or balance) in relation to per-capita GDP are now regularly reported, e.g. in the Microbanking Bulletin Wenner states that depth of outreach, specified as target maximum average loan size, has become a criteria used by the IDB for certain instruments of (rural) microfinan
35、ce policy.Financial sustainability of the financial institution and outreach to the poor are only two of the policy objectives of microfinance. The third policy objective relates to the impact of financial systems development, particularly on poverty reduction. When policy intervention and direct su
36、pport for institution building requires public investments funded either by domestic or foreign taxes or donations, the question arises about the payoff or impact, for example in terms of economic growth and alleviation of poverty and food insecurity.Institutional innovation in microfinance followin
37、g the new paradigm has relied on financial support by donors and governments and by other social investors such as philanthropic foundations. In fact, many, but not all, MFIs that reach large numbers of female and male clients below the poverty line require continued state or donor transfers to full
38、y cover costs Moreover, most, if not all, of the MFIs featured in the Microbanking Bulletin that already reached financial sustainability have required public investment at some point in their existence, be it to enable technical assistance or to receive capital for going to scale so as to reduce un
39、it costs. Some may consider these funds provided by governments, donors and other social investors as subsidies (with a negative connotation), but from a policy perspective- these funds constitute public investment (be it good or bad investment) in institution and systems building. Such publicinvest
40、ments are justified from a public policy perspective if the discounted social benefits of public investment in microfinance are expected to outweigh the social costs. These costs include the opportunity costs of foregoing the net social benefits of other public investments, such as in primary educat
41、ion . The subsidy dependence index has become a widely accepted operational measure to quantify the amount of social costs involved in supporting the operations of a financial institutionAddressing the policy question of whether such public investments are economically not financially- sustainable r
42、equires a comparison of social costs with social benefits. This consideration raises welfare impact as an important third objective of microfinance. The triangle of microfinance, which reflects the three objectives of financial sustainability, outreach, and impact, is represented in Figure 1.MFIs at
43、tempt to contribute to these objectives (either indirectly through pursuance of financial sustainability leading to scale and serving many clients or directly through targeting poorer segments of the population) but many stress one particular objective over the other two. Donors, governments, and ot
44、her social investors also differ in their relative emphasis on the three objectives. Some MFIs may produce large impacts (especially if financial services are coupled with non-financial services addressing other constraints of the poor) but achieve limited outreach. Others may make smaller impacts b
45、ut are highly financially sustainable with a large breadth of outreach, and investments in such institutions may have a high cost efficiency in reducing poverty. The potential trade-offs between depth of outreach and financial sustainability have been noted, but they may also exist between impact an
46、d financial sustainability. As Sharma and Buchenrieder argue, the impact of finance can be enhanced through complementary non financial services, such as business or marketing services or training of borrowers that raise the profitability of loan financed projects. Complementary services are sometim
47、es offered by MFIs but supplying them increases the complexity of the operation and its costs, thereby foregoing efficiency gains from specialization and jeopardizing financial sustainability if the additional costs are not covered by borrowers (which almost never happens).There may also be trade-of
48、fs between impact and depth of outreach. The impact assessment studies reviewed by Sharma and Buchenrieder suggest that the very poor can benefit from microfinance largely by smoothing their consumption through improved management of their savings and through borrowing. Those just above or justbelow
49、 the poverty line can use loans more effectively for productive purposes, which ultimately raise their income and asset base. Thus, expanding financial services may improve the welfare of the very poor, but not necessarily lift them out of poverty because of their lack of access to markets, technolo
50、gy, knowledge, and other factors that expand the production frontier.These potential trade-offs exist in urban as well as rural finance, and must be addressed when financial institutions develop their business plans and decide between marketing their services to only the very poor, to a mix of clien
51、ts clustered around the poverty line, or to owners of small- and medium-size enterprises. This raises the question of what outcome is considered most socially desirable or optimal. And giving an answer “is a matter of value judgment” (Morduch, 1999c). For example, is public support more desired for
52、MFIs that specifically target the poor, such as those in Bangladesh that use specific wealth criteria in an attempt to exclude those living above the poverty line?These questions on trade-offs arise when donors and policy-makers consider investing in rural finance.There are also potential synergies
53、among the three objectives of microfinance policy. First, financial sustainability is likely to be perceived by potential clients as a critical indicator of MFI permanence, and will influence their decision about whether it is worthwhile in the long run to become and stay clients. Thus, greater fina
54、ncial sustainability can positively influence outreach. This synergy is even more important for savers who must have faith in the permanence of the institution to which they entrust their savings. No one will save with an institution that is considered temporary. Second,striving for financial sustai
55、nability forces MFIs to be sensitive to client demand and induces them to improve products, operations, and outreach. Better financial products, in turn, generate greater economic benefits for clients, and thus greater impact.Clearly, both the institutionalist and welfarist group among microfinance
56、have good arguments, and can provide empirical evidence supporting their favored synergies or trade-offs. However, only a public-welfare perspective can consistently unite these different arguments. In addition, a public welfare perspective using cost-benefit-analysis- can, beyond micro and rural fi
57、nance, help overcome constraints in other areas (communications, markets, health, and education, etc) which hinder the economic,social and human development of the poor and, also of micro and rural finance.The outer circle represents the external environment including the macro-economic and sectoral
58、 policies that affect directly or indirectly the performance of financial institutions. Innovations at the institutional level (the inner circle) and improvements in the policy environment (the outer circle) contribute to improving the overall performance of the financial system and its institutions
59、.While finance is certainly not charity, institution-building and innovation can be significantly fostered by public investment. Such investment has to be appraised with the same evaluation criteria as for any other public investment. The social benefit-cost ratio of public support for MFIs will be
60、affected by many factors, including the macro policy, socio-economic and agro-ecological environment. Some environments may be so hostile to financial-sector development that public investments in MFIs will certainly generate a negative social return, whereas in others the same investment can be hig
61、hly profitable.譯 文:主題:農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng)農(nóng)村金融機(jī)構(gòu)的模型農(nóng)業(yè)和經(jīng)濟(jì)增長、糧食安全并消除貧困之農(nóng)村金融的角色雖然農(nóng)業(yè)是呈下降趨勢,相比較而言,在很多發(fā)展中國家,這仍然是一個主要經(jīng)濟(jì)部門,主要出口國,和主要的雇主,尤其是對窮人和婦女。改善金融市場促進(jìn)農(nóng)業(yè)和農(nóng)村發(fā)展。在維持金融服務(wù)協(xié)助家庭食品安全,保持消費(fèi),從而保護(hù)或提高勞動生產(chǎn)率,最重要的生產(chǎn)要素是窮人。因?yàn)檗r(nóng)業(yè)方面強(qiáng)大的向前和向后乘數(shù)效果,整個經(jīng)濟(jì),經(jīng)濟(jì)增長在農(nóng)業(yè)特別是在多個界別分組小農(nóng)利益直接或者間接的租戶,和工資勞動者,是一個關(guān)鍵的前提總體經(jīng)濟(jì)的增長并消除貧困。目前絕大多數(shù)的窮人仍然生活在農(nóng)村地區(qū)。任何學(xué)生的微觀經(jīng)濟(jì)
62、學(xué)導(dǎo)論課程或發(fā)展經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)得知進(jìn)入儲蓄、信貸和保險服務(wù)的家庭都有有利作用及其企業(yè),因此對經(jīng)濟(jì)增長特別是,小額信貸也可能導(dǎo)致更合理的增長。信貸渠道,然而,只有經(jīng)濟(jì)效益,當(dāng)這個訪問生成一個廣義的定義以后經(jīng)濟(jì)凈盈余的私人和社會成本扣除貸款條款(包括機(jī)會成本有限的公共資金替代扶貧政策)。而影響的證據(jù)信用對家庭福利、農(nóng)業(yè)技術(shù)的采用,農(nóng)業(yè)部門增長,許多實(shí)際的約束mixed4(即時間和金錢)和方法上的困難在估計(jì)的政策或影響項(xiàng)目的合理概率誤差的存在。簡單的常識告訴我們,儲戶存錢的動機(jī)不同,借款人繼續(xù)償還貸款,和客戶定期支付健康和人壽保險的保險費(fèi),實(shí)際推導(dǎo)出在長時期內(nèi)的經(jīng)濟(jì)效益。智慧和政策目標(biāo)改變農(nóng)村金融自上個世紀(jì)
63、八十年代,有了一個范式轉(zhuǎn)換的金融政策,包括農(nóng)村金融信貸從補(bǔ)貼金融體系的發(fā)展。舊范例扇形的指導(dǎo),供應(yīng)領(lǐng)導(dǎo)和補(bǔ)貼的信用證已經(jīng)根據(jù)有能力的企業(yè)家們和貧苦農(nóng)民錯誤的假定意愿支付金融服務(wù),導(dǎo)致錯誤的政策的設(shè)計(jì)和實(shí)施。撇開的新范式的需求,不從農(nóng)民和其他的企業(yè)家的意愿和能力(即按市場價格)、信用和存款保險服務(wù)的需求出發(fā)。相反,它集中于建立可持續(xù)的金融機(jī)構(gòu)和系統(tǒng),并介紹了經(jīng)營政策目標(biāo)MFIs金融的可持續(xù)性發(fā)展。新范式中承認(rèn)高昂的交易成本和風(fēng)險,部分是由于信息不對稱和道德風(fēng)險問題,對于金融中間人,客戶是供給問題的根源。因此,新范式尋找重點(diǎn)是技術(shù)和制度創(chuàng)新(包括適當(dāng)?shù)墓芾砗图罱Y(jié)構(gòu)的),以減少金融中介的成本和風(fēng)險
64、。認(rèn)識的新范式的可能是 “政府失敗”的市場(即總的來說是制度的失敗所造成),并否認(rèn)科學(xué)家提出的市場自由化,即“金融系統(tǒng)并不是壓抑自己會功能最佳”。 新范式中與金融市場的自由化(如看到關(guān)于利率形成)是一種必要的但不充分條件,能深化金融系統(tǒng)。此外,當(dāng)技術(shù)和制度創(chuàng)新需要深化金融系統(tǒng)時,服務(wù)貧困階層的需要可以很容易復(fù)制營利性的金融機(jī)構(gòu),由此產(chǎn)生的問題普遍存在并制約著私營部門的充分投資(比社會最優(yōu)水平創(chuàng)新)??傊?公共投資,扶貧(和專業(yè)人士)對農(nóng)村金融創(chuàng)新是必需的。這個問題不僅小額貸款存在,而且農(nóng)村金融也存在。因此,公共投資,農(nóng)村金融可以證明,例如,基金(行動)研究和初創(chuàng)企業(yè)良好的制度以及制度擴(kuò)張直到達(dá)
65、到在合理的時間金融可持續(xù)發(fā)展,并支持飛行員實(shí)驗(yàn)和希望的新產(chǎn)品、技術(shù)或技術(shù)支持,比如員工培訓(xùn)和轉(zhuǎn)讓的最佳途徑。建立可持續(xù)要求事業(yè)組織、社會投資機(jī)構(gòu)建立了需要長期規(guī)劃和準(zhǔn)備靈活操作視野設(shè)備以及把握時機(jī)。所需的公共投資,農(nóng)村金融體系更多的是勞動和知識密集型,并遠(yuǎn)比以往少一些資本密集型投資證明舊范例。三角小額金融借貸:金融可持續(xù)發(fā)展、擴(kuò)大服務(wù)、福利的影響全球協(xié)商一致的發(fā)展主要目的合作是中國在聯(lián)合國千年發(fā)展目標(biāo)(實(shí)現(xiàn))。這些目標(biāo)是減少貧困和改進(jìn)各種維度的貧窮(或福利,如:教育、健康、營養(yǎng)和婦女的授權(quán)。證明的邏輯框架的概念,金融部門政策因此需要符合這些主要的目標(biāo):小額信貸以及農(nóng)村金融政策已被評估對三大目標(biāo)金融可持續(xù)的、廣度和深度外展,和福利的影響。金融部門政策支持千禧年發(fā)展目標(biāo),從而減少貧困)兩種方式:間接通過支持可持續(xù)的金融系統(tǒng)的先決條件的經(jīng)濟(jì)和社會發(fā)展。這種間接路徑包括因果鏈條下,其減少貧困的論文通過經(jīng)濟(jì)增長。例之一,這些原因鏈?zhǔn)菢I(yè)主企業(yè)進(jìn)入使用金融服務(wù)創(chuàng)造額外對商品和服務(wù)的需求的窮人從而增加收入。直接通過提高窮人的進(jìn)入金融服務(wù)。政府以及捐贈人他們對自己也有所區(qū)別走有效性和效率的兩個通路。事實(shí)上,讓你可接受更多的重點(diǎn)不同
- 溫馨提示:
1: 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
2: 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
3.本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
5. 裝配圖網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- (中職)電子商務(wù)物流配送項(xiàng)目二任務(wù)1物流配送基本作業(yè)的主要模式 課件
- 列表法:《雞兔同籠》PPT課件(教育精品)
- 興業(yè)全球基金XXXX年下半年投資策略new
- 胃癌術(shù)后病人護(hù)理查房
- 擴(kuò)張性心肌病麻醉處理
- 漢語拼音語文課件1
- 公司治理第4章PPT
- 做中學(xué) 學(xué)中做-辦公自動化案例教程-模塊06 Excel 2010的基本操作—制作羊年主題日歷電子課件高教版
- 中醫(yī)內(nèi)科學(xué)課件42淋證(精品)
- 中道科技_公司規(guī)章制度_XXXX
- 中西餐禮儀三
- 調(diào)查研究與調(diào)查報(bào)告
- 客戶關(guān)系管理培訓(xùn)課件(PPT 38頁)
- 特種設(shè)備安全管理講義
- 八年級政治上冊第四單元《做誠信的人》課件人教新課標(biāo)版