稅收、交易權和交易成本[文獻翻譯]
《稅收、交易權和交易成本[文獻翻譯]》由會員分享,可在線閱讀,更多相關《稅收、交易權和交易成本[文獻翻譯](12頁珍藏版)》請在裝配圖網(wǎng)上搜索。
1、最新 精品 Word 歡迎下載 可修改原文:Taxes, Tradable Rights and Transaction CostsWith respect to market-based policy approaches, it is a widely held view that corrective taxation entails substantial. This conclusion only holds if set-up costs are singled out. It is argued that the prevalence of transaction costs i
2、s largely dependent on the design of the policy instrument, respectively the tax base or the trading regime chosen. Comparative analysis further shows that a cap-and-trade program of emission permits distributed for free, traded on a brokered market and monitored upstream is not only more effective,
3、 but also likely to entail fewer transaction costs than environmental taxes. Any attempt, in turn, to save the huge information, enforcement and compliance costs incurred by corrective taxation impairs its efficacy by severing the link between the environmental externality and the tax base.Basically
4、, there exist four policy instruments to curb pollution: direct regulation, environmental liability, ecological taxes and tradable emission rights. The latter two are similar in the sense that they are market-based instruments that use the price system to internalize environmental damages. They comp
5、are favorably to the two former approaches because they are flexible and cost-effective as formally demonstrated. Despite their similarity, most countries rely on taxes instead of tradable permits. Since the Kyoto Protocol, however, there is a renewed political and scientific interest in tradable em
6、ission rights. With this rise in public interest, the alleged complexity of the system and subsequent transaction costs are unremittingly criticized. In this article, we will assess the merits of this criticism.Taxes typically carry both an incentive and financial effect. Although the purpose of Pig
7、ouvian taxation is to bring about a change in activity and pollution levels, environmental taxes can be easily conceived as just an alternative source of revenue for the government. Assuming a low treasury preference, public support may have to be won by an environmental tax reform that balances env
8、ironmental tax revenues with tax cuts elsewhere or provides tax incentives for pollution reduction. However, this does not solve the systemic information problem. When environmental taxes are set too low, suboptimal emission reductions will result. Alternatively, high taxes will cause unwarranted de
9、adweight losses. Moreover, it has been recognized that the mere existence of an externality does not in itself merit corrective state action. Coase (1960) convincingly argued that, under certain circumstances, the reduction of spill-over effects can be achieved via private negotiations. This insight
10、 has led to the development of a new policy instrument.Transaction costs: The quest for taxonomyTransaction costs are nowadays frequently invoked to explain institutional, non-market phenomena. Many different definitions appear in the literature, offering various conceptual insights that have not be
11、en translated yet into standard cost categories. Therefore, we first take another look at the different definitions offered by various authors from which we will derive an operational and possibly complete taxonomy.The concept of transaction costs was introduced by Coase (1937) to explain why firms
12、exist as an alternative for organizing economic activity by means of exchange transactions across the market. The answer is that firms arise because there are substantial costs involved in using the market. Many different definitions appear in the literature, offering various conceptual insights tha
13、t have not been translated yet into standard cost categories. Coase was not very explicit about what he meant by these transaction costs. Since different types of costs may be borne by different players at different points in the policy process, a proper classification of transaction cost categories
14、 is important to assure that all relevant costs are accounted for. When complete, transaction cost taxonomy may also be helpful in improving policy design and management. According to Dahlman (1979), transaction costs include:search and information costs,bargaining and decision-making costs, monitor
15、ing and enforcement costs.The economic rationale of institutions lies in the reduction of those costs. This must be interpreted carefully. However, although institutions are, in principle, designed to reduce transaction costs by diminishing uncertainty, they may not succeed so. New or changing insti
16、tutions may generate, at any point in time, inconsistencies between competing institutions as well as uncertainty over future institutional changes which, in turn, are likely to lead to increasing transaction costs (Meyer, 2022). Milgrom and Roberts (1992) distinguish between two categories of trans
17、action costs. The first type arises from information asymmetries and incompleteness of contracts among parties. The second type stems from imperfect commitments or opportunistic behavior of parties.The OECD has classified transaction costs into two categories:non-policy related transaction costs, wh
18、ich are incurred by parties to voluntary (market) transactions, policy related transaction costs, which are associated with the implementation of policies.The former include the costs associated with gathering information, negotiating prices, ascertaining qualities, establishing exclusion mechanisms
19、, organizing collective actions and so on. The latter cover the costs incurred by government in gathering information, planning and designing policies, collecting revenues, distributing payments, and monitoring the outcome of policies.According to Furubotn and Richter (1997), transaction costs invol
20、ve the use of real resources that could be deployed alternatively elsewhere in the economy or the socioeconomic system. Transaction costs are pervasive at all levels and types of activity and inactivity and comprise the costs of establishing, maintaining, adapting, regulating, monitoring and enforci
21、ng rules as well as executing transactions. Interestingly, the opportunity costs of misallocated activities also fit into the category of transaction costs. They make a distinction between three types of transaction costs :the costs of using the market (market transaction costs),the costs of exercis
22、ing the right to give orders within the organization (managerial transaction costs),the costs of running and adjusting a political system (political transaction costs).Their taxonomy is the most complete to be found in the literature and comprises the costs of using the markets as introduced by Coas
23、e (1937), the managerial costs put forward by Williamson (1985) and the institutional costs discussed by North (1990). The Furubotn-Richter approach also absorbs the distinction made by Mullins and Baron (1997) between direct transaction costs (e.g. to initiate and complete a trade) and opportunity
24、costs (e.g. the loss of time and resources due to delay or managerial supervision). Furthermore, transactions entail costs ex ante (e.g. the search and information costs and the costs of negotiating and forming a contract or agreement) and ex post (e.g. the costs of monitoring and enforcing a contra
25、ct or agreement). In practice, however, ex ante costs often coincide with fixed costs and ex post costs with variable costs. It is important to recognize that the two types of costs are usually interdependent. Any attempt to reduce the former may affect the latter.Table 1. Transaction cost taxonomyT
26、ransaction costs Fixed (ex ante) Variable (ex post) Market Information costs Insurance costs Search costs Signaling costs Negotiation costs Contract costs Managerial Set-up costs Monitoring cost Enforcement costs Bonding costs Political Lobbying costs Operational costs Public support costs Complianc
27、e costs Enacting costs Delay costsSource: Based on Furutbotn and Richter (1997).In Table 1, we offer an extended classification based on the Furubotn-Richter taxonomy that is thought to include all relevant types of transaction costs. This scheme will be used for policy evaluation in the next paragr
28、aph.Comparative transaction costs analysisFrom an ecological and economic perspective, it is clear that tradable emission rights outperform environmental taxes, but the crux of the former system seems the transaction costs it entails. Rao (2021) has suggested that the systems of market based emissio
29、ns trading; even the well-developed programs in the United States, still have a long way to go before being effective in any sense because of excessive transaction costs. However, there exists no empirical evidence that transaction costs have prevented trading or significantly affected prices of per
30、mits in the United States . Moreover, the occurrence of high transaction costs in emissions trading does not imply that environmental taxation is any less susceptible. As Krutilla (1999) pointed out, the environmental economics literature still lacks a comparative assessment of transaction costs.Env
31、ironmental taxesCorrective taxation is itself not costless. All relevant transaction costs associated with environmental taxes will be discussed first. 1. Legislative costs. The decision on the instrument to be applied in environmental policy is formally the competence of the legislator who is suppo
32、sed to act to further the public interest. But politicians are also influenced by various interest groups like the polluting industry, environmental organizations and bureaucracy.2. Information costs. The literature on environmental tax policy leaves room for a possible net welfare gain of correctiv
33、e taxation. Containing the amount of information, accuracy relates to business decisions, however, some information is difficult to obtain. Information costs may further rise when differentiated taxes are to be implemented in accordance, enterprises get maximum benefit from. Finally, environmental p
34、ollution is often the result of accidents. Uncertainty also complicates the correct assessment of expected social costs.3. Search (planning) costs. First-best analysis expects the tax authority to use personalized. taxes and lump sum transfers since they do not bring additional distortions to the ec
35、onomy. Search costs can be somewhat mitigated, though, when the source can be linked to the cause of pollution. Taxing substances entails fewer information and search costs compared to personalized or incentive taxation. Search costs can be further reduced when the tax units are already identified.
36、4. Set-up costs. With the rise of the modern welfare state, the scope of taxation has increased dramatically. Consequently, governments have set up large agencies to administer and collect all types of direct and indirect taxes that touch upon almost every aspect of human life (consumption, producti
37、on, business initiative, work, home and even death). If the new environmental taxes can be levied and collected by an established tax agency, set-up costs are negligible and sunk.5. Operational costs. Negligible set-up costs do not imply that the costs of tax administration are low. Environmental ta
38、xation requires specialized personnel that gather the information discussed above, identifies the correct tax base, determines the optimal tax rate, feeds that information into the existing tax system and, if revenues are earmarked, collects the tax money and establishes a special fund. Although ove
39、rhead costs can be spread among taxpayers, the costs of operating the tax administration are certainly not negligible and rising with the complexity of the tax law.6. Negotiation costs. Although corporations and tax authorities often negotiate tax deals that may include environmental taxes and perso
40、nalized tax deductibles for abatement investments, it is assumed that these negotiations are restricted to larger companies and that no tax bargaining occurs among tax subjects. As a matter of fact, taxation is compulsory precisely to eradicate these transaction costs. Hence, negotiation costs are r
41、elatively small.7. Contract costs. No costs are incurred as a result of contracting over environmental.8. Monitoring and enforcement costs. Because polluters want to reduce the tax burden, they can choose to invest in abatement equipment (if the pay-off exceeds the tax payments), to reduce their pol
42、luting activities, to switch to non-taxed activities or to try and escape tax payments. Clearly, the environmental tax administration has to perform costly monitoring activities to ensure compliance and enforce tax payments. It is important to distinguish three different problems: tax evasion, tax a
43、voidance and tax delinquency. While tax evasion is a fraudulent effort to escape a tax obligation, tax avoidance occurs when a taxpayer adapts his behavior in a lawful manner so as to minimize tax payments. Tax delinquency refers to a (temporary) failure to pay the tax obligation.9. Compliance costs
44、. Administrative mechanisms to prevent tax evasion also lead to costs made by the taxpayers to comply with the rules. The main source of compliance costs involves recordkeeping and banking operations. Compliance costs can be substantial and are estimated, for example, at 7 percent of total income ta
45、x revenue.Conclusion: From this analysis, two main conclusions can be drawn. First, the transaction costs of environmental taxation are conditional upon the selected tax base. Although set-up costs are relatively low when drawing upon existing tax administrations, the enforcement and compliance cost
46、s are likely to be substantial. The latter costs are determined by the tax rules complexity which, in turn, seems a consequence of the linkage principle. The more accurately the tax base is defined, the higher the information costs and subsequent monitoring, enforcement and compliance cost. Secondly
47、, there appears a trade-off between transaction costs and the efficacy of environmental taxes. Corrective taxation, though desirable in principle, may entail prohibitively high transaction costs that can only be reduced to some extent by sacrificing its original goal viz. matching private and social
48、 costs.Source: Lode Vereeck,2022.”Taxes, Tradable Rights and Transaction Costs”, European Journal of Law and Economics No. 20,P199-223.譯文:稅收、交易權和交易成本關于以市場為基礎的政策方針,普遍認為需要糾正的稅務量很大。這個結論只能在強調(diào)設置成本的情況下成立。我們認為,交易成本的盛行在很大程度上源于選擇的計稅基數(shù)或貿(mào)易體制。進一步的對比分析表明,排放限額和交易許權的免費發(fā)放,在促成市場交易和上游監(jiān)管上不僅更有效,而且所需要的交易成本可能比環(huán)境稅更少。反過來,環(huán)
49、境外部性和計稅基礎聯(lián)系的加強,會削弱任何試圖以糾正稅收來節(jié)省巨大的信息、執(zhí)行和遵從管理費用的方法的效率?;旧嫌兴姆N政策工具可以減少污染,它們分別是:直接管理、環(huán)境責任、生態(tài)稅收和排放權交易。后兩者是相似的,因為它們都是基于市場,使用改變價格體系的手段來減少環(huán)境損失。它們比前兩個的做法更受人喜愛,是因為它們靈活且具有成本效益。雖然它們相似,但是大多數(shù)國家依靠的是稅收而不是交易許權。自從京都議定書后,國家對交易排放權產(chǎn)生了新的興趣。隨著公共利益的提高,復雜的系統(tǒng)和其隨后的交易成本受到了不斷的質疑。稅收通常既有激勵的影響,又能產(chǎn)生財務效應。盡管皮古稅的目的是為了有關活動的減少和污染程度的變化,但是
50、環(huán)境稅通常被理解為只是政府替代收入的來源。如果國庫偏好低,公眾可能支持環(huán)境稅制的改革。他們認為可以用稅收減免政策來平衡環(huán)境稅收或者運用到其他地方來激勵污染的減少。然而,這并不能解決系統(tǒng)信息的問題。當環(huán)境稅收過低時,欠佳減排的問題就會產(chǎn)生。另外,高稅收將導致不必要的損失。此外,人們認識到少量存在的某些外部性原因并不值得讓國家糾正稅收。科斯(1960)認為,在某些情況下,溢出效應的減少可以通過私下談判達成。這種認識導致了一項新的政策工具的發(fā)展。交易成本分類如今交易成本經(jīng)常用來解釋非市場現(xiàn)象。在文獻中出現(xiàn)的許多不同定義,為很多還沒有被翻譯成標準的成本項目的概念提供了認識。因此,我們應該從另外的角度看
51、看不同作者給出的不同定義,這為我們完成分類提供了可操作性??扑梗?937)認為交易成本的概念解釋了為什么其在企業(yè)外匯交易過程中是不可替代的,即企業(yè)活動因涉及市場交易所產(chǎn)生的巨額費用。許多文獻中也總結出了各種定義,并且對于那些尚未被歸類的費用有著不同的見解。但科斯也明確地表示,他所說的不一定就是交易成本的具體意思。不同類型的企業(yè)成本組成并不相同,在不同的政策過程中,交易費用的類別是根據(jù)在成本費用中所承擔的重要程度而定的。明確交易成本的分類也可以對改進政策設計和加強管理有所幫助。據(jù)達爾曼(1979)指出,交易成本包括:搜索和信息成本,談判和決策成本,監(jiān)督和執(zhí)法成本。為了減少這些成本費用,必須將其各
52、組成部分解釋清楚。盡管通過不確定性的原則,各組成部分間因相互協(xié)調(diào)而減少了部分交易成本,但有時也可能不會成功。無論在任何時候,新產(chǎn)品或更新的產(chǎn)品與原有產(chǎn)品之間都存在競爭矛盾,而變革的不確定性,很可能反過來導致交易成本的增加(邁耶,2022)。米爾格羅姆和羅伯次(1992)將交易成本劃分為兩類。第一類是由于信息的不對稱性和合同中條款的不完整性產(chǎn)生的,第二類則是因為承諾的不完善或者說當事方的機會主義行為而產(chǎn)生的。另外,經(jīng)濟組織將交易成本分為兩類:非相關的交易成本,雙方自愿交易(市場政策)導致的相關成本,政策相關的交易成本,執(zhí)行有關政策所需要付出的成本。前者包括了收集資料、進行議價、確定素質、建立排斥
53、機制、組織集體行動等過程。后者包括了由政府承擔的信息收集的成本、規(guī)劃和制定政策、繳費收入、分期付款和政策監(jiān)測下的結果。呂博騰和瑞切爾(1997)則認為,交易成本是指在經(jīng)濟制度下,所涉及的可以真正調(diào)動資源所產(chǎn)生的費用。交易成本涉及很多方面,包括設備的建立、維護、調(diào)整和規(guī)范,以及執(zhí)行并監(jiān)督交易活動中各項規(guī)則運用的全部過程。有趣的是,在錯誤配置下的交易活動所產(chǎn)生的成本也能歸入到適合的機會成本當中。他們根據(jù)交易成本之間的區(qū)別也將之分為三類:使用市場(市場交易成本)的費用,組織內(nèi)部發(fā)布命令權的費用(管理交易成本),運行和調(diào)整政治系統(tǒng)的費用(政治交易成本)。這種分類是最完整的,他們的文獻中包括了科斯(19
54、37)的有關介紹、威廉森(1985)提出的管理費用的知識點以及羅斯(1990)提出有關市場體制方面的成本費用的論點。呂博騰和瑞切爾的分類方法里也涵蓋了穆林斯和拜倫(1997)所作的直接交易成本(如啟動和完成交易)和機會成本(如由于延誤或監(jiān)督管理損失的時間和資源)的區(qū)別。此外,交易成本需要區(qū)分是在事前(如形成合同或協(xié)議之前搜索信息的費用和談判的成本)還是事后(如監(jiān)測和強制執(zhí)行合同或協(xié)議的費用)。但在實踐中,事前成本往往配合著固定費用,而事后成本則為可變費用。重要的是要認識到,這兩種費用通常是相互依存的,任何試圖減少前者的舉動都可能會影響到后者。表1.交易成本的分類交易成本 固定(事前) 可變(事
55、后)-市場 -信息成本 -保險費用-搜索成本-信號費用-談判成本-合同成本-管理 -設置成本 -監(jiān)測費用-執(zhí)行成本-焊接成本-政治 -游說費用 -業(yè)務費用-公共支持成本 -遵從成本-頒布成本 -延遲成本來源:根據(jù)呂博騰和瑞切爾(1997)在表1中,我們提供了一個以呂博騰和瑞切爾分類方法為基礎擴展的方法,其中包括了所有交易成本的類型。這個將在未來一段時間內(nèi)被論證。交易成本比較分析從生態(tài)和經(jīng)濟角度來看,很明顯,生態(tài)稅收要優(yōu)于排放權交易,其中交易成本似乎是以往的制度政策所造成的。堯(2021)表明,交易成本的存在并沒有嚴重影響或阻礙美國許可證的交易價格。此外,和生態(tài)稅收相比,擁有高排放權的貿(mào)易活動并
56、不意味著會產(chǎn)生較少的交易成本。生態(tài)稅收稅收本身并非沒有成本,因此首先將所有與環(huán)境稅收有關的交易費用進行討論。(1)立法成本;制定有關政策是以促進公眾利益為前提的,所有企業(yè)則應在法律權限范圍內(nèi)采取適當?shù)男袆印5?,領導們也會受到不同利益集團的影響,如無污染企業(yè)和環(huán)境保護組織等。(2)信息成本;提出環(huán)境稅收政策是為了能夠擁有一個稅收凈收益的可能性。信息的含有量、準確度都關系到企業(yè)決策的進行。然而有的信息是很難獲得的。區(qū)別各種稅收方式,使企業(yè)獲取最大收益,信息成本就可能進一步上升。到最后,往往產(chǎn)生讓人意外的結果-環(huán)境污染。社會的不確定性也使得預期的成本評估復雜化了。(3)搜索(計劃)成本。首先最好的
57、分析預計是稅收機關使用個性化方式。稅收一次性全額轉移是因為它們不會帶來額外的經(jīng)濟負擔。盡管來源和污染原因聯(lián)系在一起,但是搜索成本還是可以有所減輕的。同個性化和激勵稅收相比,稅收物質需要更少的信息和搜索成本。當稅收部門已經(jīng)確定時,搜索成本可以進一步減少。(4) 設置成本。隨著現(xiàn)代福利國家的興起,征稅范圍已大大增加。因此,政府已經(jīng)組建了大型機構來管理和收集所有類型的直接和間接稅,這幾乎觸及了人們生活的方方面面(生產(chǎn)、消費、經(jīng)營主動性、工作、家庭,甚至死亡)。如果新的環(huán)境稅可以由建立的稅務機關來征收,設置和沉沒成本則可以忽略不計。(5)業(yè)務費用。稅收征管的比率比較低并不意味著設置成本就可以忽略不計。
58、環(huán)境稅收需要專門人員收集資料,結合現(xiàn)行稅制,討論并確定正確的稅基及最優(yōu)稅率,通過征收的稅款設立特別基金。雖然管理費用可以由納稅人負責,但稅收經(jīng)營管理的成本仍然不容忽視,其復雜性也在不斷上升。(6)談判費用;企業(yè)和稅收機關經(jīng)常對有關交易的稅收進行談判,其中可能包括減少生態(tài)稅收和減免個性化投資的稅收,但這些談判僅限于大公司。事實上,稅收的強制性正是為了消除這些交易成本。因此,談判的成本相對較小。(7)合同費用;任何費用支出是對環(huán)境承包的結果。(8)監(jiān)測和執(zhí)行成本;由于污染者要減輕稅收負擔,他們可能選擇減少設備投資(如薪酬超過付稅),減少污染活動以轉變成非征稅活動來試圖逃避交稅。顯然,執(zhí)行稅收征管必
59、須要密集,這樣才能確保人們遵守稅收制度。其中,最重要的就是區(qū)分三種不同的問題:逃稅、避稅和稅收犯罪。逃稅是欺詐性的行為,即努力逃避稅收義務;避稅是納稅人用合適行為、合法的方式,以盡量減少納稅;稅收犯罪是指(臨時)未履行繳付稅款的義務。 (9) 遵從成本。行政機制防止逃稅還會導致由納稅人為遵守規(guī)則付出的成本。遵從成本的主要來源包括記錄和銀行業(yè)務。遵從成本可能數(shù)量比較大,但是可以被估計和預測。比如,占稅收總額的百分之七。 結論:通過以上的分析,主要可以得出兩個結論。首先,稅收可以通過交易的成本選擇稅基。雖然稅收的設置成本相對較低并由現(xiàn)有的稅收當局制訂,但要執(zhí)行和遵從成本可能是巨大的。稅收規(guī)則的復雜性決定了費用是可變的,所以,我們可以將它充分利用起來。其次,交易成本和生態(tài)稅收兩者之間似乎可以相互取舍。調(diào)整稅收,雖然可能帶來過高的費用,但是能在一定程度上減少其最初的交易成本,也是一種可取的方法。出處:洛德弗瑞克. 稅收、交易權和交易成本.歐洲法律和經(jīng)濟,2022(20):P199-223。
- 溫馨提示:
1: 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
2: 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權益歸上傳用戶所有。
3.本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預覽,若沒有圖紙預覽就沒有圖紙。
4. 未經(jīng)權益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
5. 裝配圖網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負責。
6. 下載文件中如有侵權或不適當內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
7. 本站不保證下載資源的準確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- (中職)電子商務物流配送項目二任務1物流配送基本作業(yè)的主要模式 課件
- 列表法:《雞兔同籠》PPT課件(教育精品)
- 興業(yè)全球基金XXXX年下半年投資策略new
- 胃癌術后病人護理查房
- 擴張性心肌病麻醉處理
- 漢語拼音語文課件1
- 公司治理第4章PPT
- 做中學 學中做-辦公自動化案例教程-模塊06 Excel 2010的基本操作—制作羊年主題日歷電子課件高教版
- 中醫(yī)內(nèi)科學課件42淋證(精品)
- 中道科技_公司規(guī)章制度_XXXX
- 中西餐禮儀三
- 調(diào)查研究與調(diào)查報告
- 客戶關系管理培訓課件(PPT 38頁)
- 特種設備安全管理講義
- 八年級政治上冊第四單元《做誠信的人》課件人教新課標版